FeaturedIssues

Balancing the value of tariffs

While US consumers benefited from lower prices on imported goods, these widely dispersed gains were less salient than the concentrated pain of factory closures and job losses in regions exposed to import competition.

By Pinelopi Koujianou Goldberg
Special to The Times Kuwait


US President-elect Donald Trump’s promise to impose a 60% tariff on imports from China, and a 10-20% tariff on all other imports has triggered a public debate about whether such policies are really so bad. After all, a tariff is a consumption tax, and most economists favor taxes on consumption over income taxes, since the former are more efficient and easier to administer.

But tariffs have significant drawbacks. Since they tax only imported products, they distort markets by shifting resources from more efficient foreign producers to less efficient domestic firms. This inefficiency comes at the expense of consumers, and like most consumption taxes, tariffs are regressive, placing a heavier burden on low-income households that spend a larger share of their income on consumer goods.

Still, tariffs do have political appeal. Critics of globalization in advanced economies have long argued that the efficiency gains from recent decades of trade liberalization have been modest, relative to the disruptions caused. While US consumers benefited from lower prices on imported goods, particularly from China, these widely dispersed gains were less salient than the concentrated pain of factory closures and job losses in regions exposed to import competition.

Against this backdrop, higher tariffs might not look so bad. Perhaps reversing globalization’s modest efficiency gains could redirect income toward domestic producers and workers. Perhaps tariffs’ regressive effects can be addressed with policies like exemptions for de minimis imports (valued under $800). Besides, while prices of taxed imports would increase, American consumers in the past did not seem especially appreciative of trade’s role in making the goods they consumed more affordable.

The problem with such arguments is that they ignore the current macroeconomic context. Inflation over the last three years has increased consumer sensitivity to price changes. Voters today will be far more attuned to the inflationary pressures of tariffs than they were in the past. While proponents of new tariffs claim that China would bear the brunt of the financial burden, the evidence from the 2018-19 tariffs shows otherwise: US consumers bore most of the cost. Considering that the previous tariffs were 10-25 percent, the proposed 60 percent levy might shift some costs to China, but American consumers would still feel the sting.

Even if US prices remained unchanged, unintended consequences could follow. If broad-based tariffs led to a sharp depreciation of China’s currency, the stronger dollar would make Chinese imports relatively cheaper. This may partly offset the higher prices caused by tariffs, but it would undermine the original goal of making US manufacturing more competitive. Meanwhile, the stronger dollar would hurt US exports, worsening the trade deficit.

This suggests that the multiple goals currently advertised for tariffs—reshoring manufacturing, reducing the trade deficit, generating revenue, lessening America’s reliance on China, and forcing China into negotiations, all while minimizing the impact on consumers—often conflict with one another. This is because tariffs affect the US economy through prices. To boost US competitiveness or reduce the deficit, tariffs must raise import prices—a politically toxic outcome today.

Reducing America’s reliance on China is also complex, given that Chinese-made intermediates are embedded in many goods exported to the US from third countries. Since 2018-19, China and several ‘bystander’ countries have registered robust export growth despite tariffs. The proposed new tariffs might affect only direct Chinese exports to the US, not to other countries. Broadening them to more countries to curb China’s reach would exacerbate price pressures, because there would be fewer substitution possibilities for US consumers and businesses.

The argument for tariffs as a revenue-generating mechanism is interesting and novel (in the sense that it has not been used for many centuries). But it does not hold up. Tariffs cannot possibly replace income taxes as a source of revenue: the scale of the income tax base is roughly an order of magnitude larger than the scale of imports. Still, tariffs could generate some government revenue, with China potentially bearing part of the cost. If used as a short-term negotiating tactic, they could apply some economic pressure on China.

Strengthening the United States’ negotiating leverage is the most compelling argument for tariffs. The 2018-19 tariffs led to the ‘phase one’ agreement, a planned de-escalation in exchange for Chinese commitments to import more from the US and address concerns about intellectual property and technology transfers. Though the earlier tariffs marked the biggest departure from free trade since the 1930 Smoot-Hawley Act, their economic impact was modest, and the agreement allowed the US to save face.

But the 2018-19 tariffs were far from cost-free. They poisoned US-China relations, escalated tensions, pushed China into an alliance with Russia and Iran, and fueled anti-Asian sentiment domestically. They eroded America’s relationships with allies who were not consulted, and who found themselves also targeted by specific tariffs. And when all was said and done, the phase one deal’s full impact was never realized. The disruption to trade from the pandemic meant that China fell far short of its commitments to purchase goods from the US.

Today’s tariff proposals risk repeating history, only on a grander scale. The incoming administration will face a wary, inflation-sensitive public and a Chinese regime that is well prepared to pursue large-scale retaliation. Whether tariffs become a negotiating tool or a source of greater economic disruption depends on how the administration balances competing objectives. Reason and strategic foresight will be crucial.


Pinelopi Koujianou Goldberg
Pinelopi Koujianou Goldberg, a former World Bank Group chief economist and editor-in-chief of the American Economic Review, is Professor of Economics at Yale University.


Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2024.
www.project-syndicate.org



Read Today's News TODAY...
on our Telegram Channel
click here to join and receive all the latest updates t.me/thetimeskuwait




Back to top button